Zach Bleemer
@zbleemer.bsky.social
330 followers 4 following 31 posts
Assistant Professor of Economics at Princeton and NBER | Education and Economic Mobility
Posts Media Videos Starter Packs
Pinned
zbleemer.bsky.social
New study: The relative wage premium for going to college has halved for low-income Americans since 1960.

What is to blame? Rising selectivity? Tuition hikes? State disinvestment? We decompose changes in the premium since 1900 to find out.

🧵#EconTwitter nber.org/papers/w33797
Reposted by Zach Bleemer
willpjones.bsky.social
This is one of the most important, and least understood, details in the value of higher education - it's benefits are reaped very differently by rich and poor students.
Opinion | How higher education failed America’s poor
For decades, policymakers claimed to expand college access. In reality, they rerouted poor students into the least valuable degrees.
www.washingtonpost.com
Reposted by Zach Bleemer
robertkelchen.com
This depressing new NBER working paper finds that while the returns to a college education are still clearly positive for everyone, the benefits for students from lower-income families have declined over time due to fewer resources going to regional institutions.
Changes in the College Mobility Pipeline Since 1900
Founded in 1920, the NBER is a private, non-profit, non-partisan organization dedicated to conducting economic research and to disseminating research findings among academics, public policy makers, an...
www.nber.org
zbleemer.bsky.social
Interesting! You're right to point out that history is the highest-wage HUM majors, but we do put it in that category.

Most of our surveys only report one major; when they have two, we just take the first. We could randomize instead; I wonder if your EDU students would list history first or second!
zbleemer.bsky.social
If you have questions about, e.g.:

1. Things it's not: selection into college/the Ivy League/selectivity and the SAT/rising tuition;
2. Causal interpretability;
3. What about women;
4. Details on data construction;

or more, you should definitely take a look at the full study!
zbleemer.bsky.social
Thanks for reading! You can find an ungated version of the study here:

zacharybleemer.com/wp-content/u...
zacharybleemer.com
zbleemer.bsky.social
If lower-income kids still got the same relative value from going to college as in 1960 – even holding fixed *who* goes to college – then intergenerational income transmission in the US would fall ~25%.

This explains most of the decline in economic mobility since the '60s.
zbleemer.bsky.social
Altogether, changes in institutional returns (30%), major composition (25%), and two-year and for-profit composition (20%) explain most of the regressivity trend.

This is why going to college has become less valuable for poor students.
zbleemer.bsky.social
The for-profit sector peaked in the 2000s and has dramatically shrunk. But recent growth of the community colleges disproportionately holds poor students back.

Poor students' diversion to these lower-value colleges explains about 20% of the rise in collegiate regressivity.
zbleemer.bsky.social
Trend 3️⃣ explaining the rise of collegiate regressivity is the growth of community colleges and the for-profit sector.

Students who attend these schools derive lower value-added from them. Since the 1980s, those students have been disproportionately poor.
zbleemer.bsky.social
We all know that the humanities are shrinking. It turns out that most of that decline is coming from rich students.

Possibly for the first time ever, poor students are now more likely to be humanities majors than rich students.

That's bad for economic mobility.
zbleemer.bsky.social
Sometimes, like in the 1920s or the 1990s, poor and rich college students earn similar-value majors.

Today, though, poor students earn much lower-paying majors than the rich. This explains 25% of regressivity.

Two disciplines are most at fault: humanities and computer science.
zbleemer.bsky.social
Trend 2️⃣ driving collegiate regressivity is the most surprising. This one is about college majors.

There are huge differences in wage value across majors. They haven't changed much over time.

Humanities at the bottom. Engineering at the top. The gap has widened.
zbleemer.bsky.social
If colleges' value-added hadn't changed since 1960, rich and poor students would have always attended similar-value schools.

But using current value-added, poor students attend lower-value uni's.

Teaching-oriented publics' deterioration explains 30% of collegiate regressivity.
zbleemer.bsky.social
College quality varies widely: e.g. research-oriented publics have 2x the per-student revenue of teaching-oriented publics.

That money buys value. We measure colleges' "value-added": the degree to which they increase future wages.

Poor students' colleges' value has fallen.
zbleemer.bsky.social
Number 1️⃣ is about changes in colleges' quality.

Rich students have always mostly attended private and research public universities. Poor students mostly go to teaching-oriented publics.

That's still true. But the teaching-oriented publics have deteriorated in value.
zbleemer.bsky.social
We first plot the slope of the college-going premium by parental income over time. Positive numbers mean the premium is regressive.

Between 1920 and 1960, the premium was equal for the rich and poor. It's been getting more regressive since then.

Three factors explain the trend:
zbleemer.bsky.social
To identify and trace the causes of rising collegiate regressivity, we combine dozens of nationally-representative survey and admin datasets spanning 1900-2023.

The data include the parental income, college, major, and early-30s wages of hundreds of thousands of Americans.
zbleemer.bsky.social
In the early 1900s, the wage premium for going to college was the same for sons from both rich and poor families : +10 ranks (+15%) in the wage distribution.

Today, the wage premium has grown for the rich but sharply fallen for the poor. We call this "collegiate regressivity".
zbleemer.bsky.social
New study: The relative wage premium for going to college has halved for low-income Americans since 1960.

What is to blame? Rising selectivity? Tuition hikes? State disinvestment? We decompose changes in the premium since 1900 to find out.

🧵#EconTwitter nber.org/papers/w33797
Reposted by Zach Bleemer
elionimier.bsky.social
Why are wages in Paris or NYC higher than in other cities?

In a new WP with @paulinecarry.bsky.social & @bennykleinman.bsky.social, we decompose spatial disparities btw “location effects” and the local composition of workers and establishments.

New data on firm mobility + double-mover design.

🧵⬇️
nber.org
NBER @nber.org · May 15
Data on firm relocations reveal that nearly all wage differences between cities stem from the spatial sorting of workers and firms; Location-specific factors explain only 2–5 percent, from Pauline Carry, Benny Kleinman, and Elio Nimier-David https://www.nber.org/papers/w33779
Reposted by Zach Bleemer
jrothst.bsky.social
We are hiring an education researcher to join the @capolicylab.bsky.social and @berkeleycshe.bsky.social teams. You'll work on projects using administrative data relating to California higher education. Here's more information: capolicylab.org/careers/rese...
Reposted by Zach Bleemer
anderskjelsrud.bsky.social
**New working paper**

How does the under-representation of females in Economics affect the career trajectory of female Ph.D. students?

Sahar Parsa and I look at this in a new working paper by exploring sabbatical leaves taken by female professors at top-50 US Econ departments.
zbleemer.bsky.social
I will discuss recent trends in meritocracy, access, and the allocation of US higher education on a livestreamed ASSA panel tomorrow (Sunday) at 8 am PST, 11 EST.

Livestream here: www.aeaweb.org/conference/l...
ASSA 2025 Live-Streamed Sessions
www.aeaweb.org